Thursday 14 July 2011

Agricultural Employment, Production & Income of the Nagas: A Case of Nagaland State


Agricultural Employment, Production and Income of the Nagas: A Case of Nagaland State

Marchang Reimeingam
Morung Express, Nagaland, 9th May 2009

The economy of Nagaland, a hilly state with a geographical area of 16,579 sq. km., is basically agrarian where employment is predominated by traditional agriculture sector. In such situation a large section of workers are engage in it, farm inputs are crude and traditional, productivity is low, subsistence products are produced, marketable surplus are insignificant, etc. However, with an increase in demand of various agricultural products and the shortest of its supply resulted to an automatically increase in the market price of the products. In the process a modern farm inputs such as tractors, high yielding seeds, fertilizers, etc are adopted as a result farm productivity and production are raised leading to an increase in agricultural income of the state.
According to the Forest Survey of India in 1999 as large as 85.43 percent of the state’s geographical area is covered by forest. The total cropped area for all crops was only 260,000 hectares in 1998. Of this a larger share of area is under jhumming cultivation. According to the census of India the population size of the state is close to 2 million in 2001. It is growing at an alarming rate of 4.98 percent per annum during 1991-2001 affecting the structure of employment and nature of unemployment that is contributed by both the natural growth and influx of migrants. This resulted to a sharp increase in the density of population from 73 persons per sq. km. in 1991 to 120 in 2001. Due to the growing population the density of agricultural workers (ratio between agricultural workers and geographical areas or food grain areas, based on Population and Agricultural Censuses) has also considerably increase. (Here area, production and yield refer for total food grains.) Agricultural density (ratio between agricultural workers and geographical areas) has increased from 23 agricultural workers per sq. km. in 1991 to 35 in 2001. Similarly, agricultural density (ratio between agricultural workers and food grain areas) has increased from 2.26 to 2.75 agricultural workers per hectares during the same period. Meanwhile, it is also noteworthy that agriculture practices are mostly jhumming. The increase in agricultural density is because of the increased in population where excess supply of labour are pressed onto the non-extendable agricultural land due to an unavailability of employment in non-agricultural sector. The increase of agricultural density means a decline of per capita availability of land or decline of the size of land holdings which reflects to underemployment particularly among those small or medium land operators.
Majority of the workers are primarily engaged in agriculture sector. Of the total workers (main and marginal) as large as 68.38 percent were engaged as agricultural workers (cultivators plus agricultural labourers) in 2001 which has declined from 74.27 percent in 1991. The decline is contributed by an increase in agricultural density which forces some previous agricultural workers to work in other sectors. The growing labour force can further unable to absorb in agriculture sector so they had to seek or take jobs in other sector as a result the share of agriculture workers has declined. It must also be true that there exist a wide spread disguised unemployment as a result of high agricultural density. The declined is, thus, because of the implication of the principle of “law of diminishing returns” that more and more people when pressed to work on a given piece of land, their marginal (and average) productivity declines. Nevertheless, in line of Mellor’s definition of traditional agriculture of labour intensive, the existing large share of agricultural workers indicates a traditional character.
The income derived from the agriculture sector is disproportionate when compared to the magnitude of employment in this sector. This is most likely due to the low per capita agricultural production which is resulted by the high agricultural density associated with low productivity. Low productivity is a result of non-adoption of improved/high yielding inputs, dependence on monsoon for irrigation, non-utilisation of bio-chemical inputs, showed crops with long gestation period, etc. Moreover, the lack of technical-know-how for improving agricultural productivity plays a significant role for low production.  The contribution of income (Net State Domestic Production based on data provided by planning commission) from agriculture was 18.53 percent in 1991 which has considerably increased to 30.31 percent in 2001. As a result the per capita income of agricultural workers (ratio between Agricultural Income and Agricultural Workers) has also considerably increased from merely Rs. 1,151 in 1991 to Rs. 11,661 in 2001. This increase is due to the general rising price level (Note that NSDP for 1991 is at 1980-81 price and for 2001 is at 1993-94 price). The low level of income contribution by agriculture implies a continuation of practice of traditional method of cultivation with insignificant use of modern farm inputs resulting to a slow progress in production. While, agricultural productivity (yield) has increased thereby raising production over the years. This can be explained by a higher decadal growth of production (40.32 percent during 1991 to 2001) than the growth of agricultural land/area (24.12 percent). The growth of production is lower than the growth of population (64.53 percent) thereby reducing the per capita food grain production and its growth (-14.71) during 1991 to 2001. The per capita food grain production (ratio between food grain production and population based on data from Area and Production of Principal Crops in India and Population Census) has declined from 163 to 139 kg per person during 1991 to 2001. In order to raise per capita production various measures such as reducing population growth and utilisation of improved techniques of farm inputs and dissemination of technical-know-how and market information need to be undertaken.
In short, the share of agricultural workers has declined due to the growing agricultural density; however, majority of the workers continue to engage in agriculture practicing traditional cultivation. The corresponding share of agriculture income has increased as a result of gradual growth in production and rise in the price of agricultural products. 
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

For citation: Marchang Reimeingam, Agricultural Employment, Production and Income of the Nagas: A Case of Nagaland State, Morung Express, Nagaland, 9th May 2009.

No comments:

Post a Comment